Skip to content

wrossmorrow/bneqpri

Repository files navigation

bneqpri

Python code for computing Bertrand-Nash equilibrium prices with "mixed" logit models. The implemented method is the fixed-point iteration derived and discussed in the papers Fixed-Point Approaches to Computing Bertrand-Nash Equilibrium Prices Under Mixed-Logit Demand (Operations Research, 2011) and Finite purchasing power and computations of Bertrand–Nash equilibrium prices (Computational Optimization and Applications, 2015); there's also a super verbose working paper on the arxiv. You can get the whole gist from the first paper, the second introduces finer grained details related to treatment of "budgets" in the choice model (under regularity conditions). The basic idea is that there is a particular fixed-point equation for simultaneous stationarity (the necessary conditions for equilibrium prices) that is provably norm-coercive and generates steps that are never orthogonal to the combined-gradient. Iterating such steps appears to be a strong, matix-inversion-free alternative to Newton-type methods as discussed at some length in the papers, although there is no convergence proof.

Dependencies

Using this repo requires python3 and numpy.

Installation

This project is on pypi and thus you can use pip:

pip install bneqpri

If you want to build from the repo, do

just build

if you have just. Or

poetry build

with poetry.

You can run tests with

just unit-test

or review the standard-ish pytest command in the justfile.

Solver "tests" are different, and not formally conditions for code correctness. You can review them in test/solver/test_solver.py and/or run them with

just solver-test --capture no

Command-Line Usage

$ python -m bneqpri --help
usage: __main__.py [-h] [--format {sequential,indexed}] [--firms FIRMS]
                   [--products PRODUCTS] [--individuals INDIVIDUALS]
                   [--linear-utility] [--initial-prices INITIAL_PRICES]
                   [--prices PRICES] [--ftol FTOL] [--iters ITERS] [-q]

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 

Bertrand-Nash Equilibrium Prices Solver (with Finite Purchasing Power / Budgets)

Method from: 

Morrow, W.R. & Skerlos, S.J. Fixed-Point Approaches to Computing Bertrand-Nash Equilibrium 
Prices Under Mixed-Logit Demand. Operations Research 59(2) (2011).
https://doi.org/10.1287/opre.1100.0894)

Morrow, W.R. Finite purchasing power and computations of Bertrand–Nash equilibrium prices.
Computational Optimization and Applications 62, 477–515 (2015). 
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10589-015-9743-7           

Note this software is provided AS-IS under the GPL v2.0 License. Contact the author
with any questions. Copyright 2020+ W. Ross Morrow. 

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 

optional arguments:
  -h, --help            show this help message and exit
  --format {sequential,indexed}
                        Format input files are written in. Sequential presumes firms' products 
                        are listed sequentially, indexed means the header for product and individual file has _
                        indices describing the firm and product for the column. NOT YET IMPLEMENTED.
  --firms FIRMS         File describing the number of firms and the number of products they each offer
  --products PRODUCTS   File describing the number of products and their unit costs
  --individuals INDIVIDUALS
                        File describing the number of individuals, their budgets, price sensitivities, and utilities
  --linear-utility      Presume the utility is linear in the price coefficient, instead of using budgets
  --initial-prices INITIAL_PRICES
                        File with initial prices to use when starting iterations
  --prices PRICES       File with the computed prices, written upon solve
  --ftol FTOL           Solve tolerance, will terminate when |p-c-z(p)| < ftol
  --iters ITERS         Maximum number of iterations
  -q, --quiet           Don't print information to the console

Quick Start

Run by specifying three csv files, describing the firm structure, the products (costs only now), and the utilities.

The firm file should be a single-line csv file (not including header) with the number of firms F, followed by the number of products offered by each firm. E.g,

3 , 3 , 5 , 4

for 3 firms, the first of which offers 3 products, the second 5, and the third 4. Spaces are ignored. The firm file thus has F+1 columns.

The product file is another single-line csv file (not including header) and should contain the number of products J, followed by the costs for each of the J products. J must equal the sum of the number of products offered by each firm in the firm file. E.g.,

12 , 1 , 1 , 1 , 2 , 2 , 2 , 2 , 2 , 3 , 3 , 3

The products file thus has J+1 columns. Note that this code presumes the products are ordered by firm. In our example above, we've chosen unit costs such that firm 1's 3 products all cost "1" to make, firm 2's "2", and firm 3's "3". Note that the monetary units are irrelevant as long as they are consistent with utilities and budgets, and prices are computed in whatever units costs are in.

Models with Finite Purchasing Power / Budgets

The utilities file is the most complicated, having as many rows as the number of individuals I (not including header) and 2+J columns. In each row i, which corresponds to an individual i, the first column should be the budget for that individual b[i], the second the price sensitivity a[i], and the remaining J columns have the total non-price utility of all the part-worths of the features for each product in columns 2 for product 1, 2+1 for product 2, etc comprising a matrix V[i,j] of product utilities (except price). Again, products are ordered sequentially by firms.

The utility function for choices used here is, for now, presumed to be

U[i,j](p) = a[i] log( b[i] - p ) + V[i,j]

when there is a budget. There is an outside good with unit value; any non unit value should be absorbed into the non-price utility. A word of warning, the price sensitivity must be positive for all individuals and probably needs to be larger than one for all individuals.

Linear Utility

We also include an implementation and command line flag (--linear-utility) for linear utility models

U[i,j](p) = a[i] p + V[i,j]

Note that here a[i] should be negative and you should not specify the b[i] column in the utilities file (thus it will have only 1+J columns, not 2+J).

Examples

Example files of each are provided in the example directory here, and you can run them all as follows:

$ bash examples.sh 

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 

2020-10-02T20:26:37.144882 :: Modeling 1000 individuals, 10 firms, 144 products, linear utility no budget
2020-10-02T20:26:37.687914 :: Solved in 34/1000 steps, 0.542978048324585 seconds
2020-10-02T20:26:37.687948 :: fixed-point satisfaction |p-c-z| = 7.961977299686396e-09
2020-10-02T20:26:37.688401 :: (probable) equilibium prices written to examples/linear/1000-10-144/prices.csv

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 


- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 

2020-10-02T20:26:37.918779 :: Modeling 1000 individuals, 5 firms, 79 products, linear utility no budget
2020-10-02T20:26:38.287736 :: Solved in 28/1000 steps, 0.36890220642089844 seconds
2020-10-02T20:26:38.287766 :: fixed-point satisfaction |p-c-z| = 8.772539583645766e-09
2020-10-02T20:26:38.288218 :: (probable) equilibium prices written to examples/linear/1000-5-79/prices.csv

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 


- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 

2020-10-02T20:26:38.465683 :: Modeling 50 individuals, 3 firms, 53 products, linear utility no budget
2020-10-02T20:26:38.532921 :: Solved in 44/1000 steps, 0.06718897819519043 seconds
2020-10-02T20:26:38.532958 :: fixed-point satisfaction |p-c-z| = 6.891536230568818e-09
2020-10-02T20:26:38.533299 :: (probable) equilibium prices written to examples/linear/50-3-53/prices.csv

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 


- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 

2020-10-02T20:26:38.730063 :: Modeling 500 individuals, 3 firms, 40 products, linear utility no budget
2020-10-02T20:26:39.188571 :: Solved in 78/1000 steps, 0.4584488868713379 seconds
2020-10-02T20:26:39.188606 :: fixed-point satisfaction |p-c-z| = 8.38127345303974e-09
2020-10-02T20:26:39.188918 :: (probable) equilibium prices written to examples/linear/500-3-40/prices.csv

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 


- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 

2020-10-02T20:26:39.457582 :: Modeling 1000 individuals, 10 firms, 148 products, nonlinear utility with budget
2020-10-02T20:26:51.156455 :: Solved in 32/1000 steps, 11.698816061019897 seconds
2020-10-02T20:26:51.156493 :: fixed-point satisfaction |p-c-z| = 8.289176345321891e-09
2020-10-02T20:26:51.156979 :: (probable) equilibium prices written to examples/budgets/1000-10-148/prices.csv

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 


- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 

2020-10-02T20:26:51.393449 :: Modeling 1000 individuals, 5 firms, 68 products, nonlinear utility with budget
2020-10-02T20:27:03.496671 :: Solved in 73/1000 steps, 12.103170156478882 seconds
2020-10-02T20:27:03.496717 :: fixed-point satisfaction |p-c-z| = 9.146744250898564e-09
2020-10-02T20:27:03.497178 :: (probable) equilibium prices written to examples/budgets/1000-5-68/prices.csv

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 


- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 

2020-10-02T20:27:03.689047 :: Modeling 50 individuals, 3 firms, 41 products, nonlinear utility with budget
2020-10-02T20:27:03.818524 :: Solved in 20/1000 steps, 0.12943220138549805 seconds
2020-10-02T20:27:03.818557 :: fixed-point satisfaction |p-c-z| = 5.774188682750037e-09
2020-10-02T20:27:03.818899 :: (probable) equilibium prices written to examples/budgets/50-3-41/prices.csv

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 


- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 

2020-10-02T20:27:04.019609 :: Modeling 500 individuals, 3 firms, 44 products, nonlinear utility with budget
2020-10-02T20:27:08.500028 :: Solved in 78/1000 steps, 4.48035192489624 seconds
2020-10-02T20:27:08.500067 :: fixed-point satisfaction |p-c-z| = 8.66341531846615e-09
2020-10-02T20:27:08.500400 :: (probable) equilibium prices written to examples/budgets/500-3-44/prices.csv

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 

Details

Detailed README content TBD

TBD

  • Tons more tests
  • Implement second-order sufficiency check for computed prices
  • Figure out why numpy syntax isn't computing G'm terms correctly

Contact

W. Ross Morrow

Copyright 2020+

About

Fixed-Point Solver for Bertrand-Nash Equilibrium Pricing Problems

Resources

License

Stars

Watchers

Forks

Releases

No releases published

Packages

No packages published